[Date Prev][Date Next][Thread Prev][Thread Next][Date Index][Thread Index]
Re: [dvd-discuss] 2001 Best year ever for movies
- To: dvd-discuss(at)cyber.law.harvard.edu
- Subject: Re: [dvd-discuss] 2001 Best year ever for movies
- From: "Peter D. Junger" <junger(at)samsara.law.cwru.edu>
- Date: Mon, 11 Mar 2002 02:56:15 -0500
- In-reply-to: Your message of "Thu, 07 Mar 2002 18:40:27 EST." <Pine.LNX.4.33.0203071835380.22264-100000@qwe3.math.cmu.edu>
- Reply-to: dvd-discuss(at)cyber.law.harvard.edu
- Sender: owner-dvd-discuss(at)cyber.law.harvard.edu
Scott A Crosby writes:
: On Wed, 6 Mar 2002, mickey wrote:
:
: >
: >
: > http://www.foxnews.com/story/0,2933,47200,00.html
: >
: > How many films did the major film studios make in 2001? By the "two out
: > of ten" guide, around 100?
:
: Both sets of numbers are completely believable. Most films flop. Only a
: few films actually make money, but those that do, make it BIG. Same thing
: with large-scale commercial music. Most bands lose money, but those ones
: are funded by the ones that make money.
:
: So, if we have 10 movies. All cost $10M to make. 2 make $50M, the rest
: make $3M, then it is perfectly true that we can have a great year,
: making a profit of 24%, yet, have 80% of our movies make barely a third of
: their money back. :)
:
: So, Valenti is complaining about the risks of the movie business. But in a
: self-serving fashion in front of congress, cause its ALWAYS been that way.
The economics of the motion picture industry is wierd:
See <http://hypatia.ss.uci.edu/econ/personnel/devany/BESummary.html>
\begin{quotation}
Motion pictures are fragile products whose lives are unpredictable
and brief. Less than one out of six films lasts more than two weeks
on theater screens and only one in twenty lasts longer than fifteen
weeks. More than 80 per cent of revenues earned by 300 films were
earned by just four films. Stars and big budgets guarantee only
that a film's run will begin on many screens; from there on a
film's run is like a parachute jump---if the film doesn't open, it
is dead.
This paper quantifies the stark uncertainty of motion picture
revenues and shows how the industry is organized to deal with it.
The industry is geared to adapt the number of engagements and the
prices charged to theater operators to the information revealed in
weekly revenue reports. There is no other way to discover how good
a film is than to put it on screens and let the audience decide.
As audiences discover their preferences and spread information,
they produce complex revenue dynamics. Information cascades can
carry a film to explosive growth or to swift failure. This dynamic
demand discovery requires adaptive supply and pricing and the
industry's contracts and licensing terms are designed to support
these adaptations.
The statistical model reveals that the distribution of revenues
among competing films follows a dynamic path so complex and variable
that the only model capable of accounting for them is the
Bose-Einstein distribution of statistical physics. Audiences tend to
behave over the course of a film's run like the particles falling
into urns in a statistical physics model. In the Bose-Einstein
process it is equally likely that the particles (audience) will fall
into a few urns (movies) as it is for them to be distributed in any
other way.
Ultimately, the probability that a new viewer will go a particular
film depends positively on the number who have already seen it and on
the distribution of viewers over all the other films it is competing
with. These dynamics let films leverage early successes (in revenue
terms) into greater success in later trials. The Bose-Einstein
process leads to extreme inequality in the final distribution of total
motion picture revenues, resulting in a so-called power law also known
to economists as the Pareto distribution.
These results show that conventional thinking about the revenue
expectations of motion pictures is misleading. Revenues do not follow
"normal" or bell curves; the revenue distribution has no
characteristic scale, so it is wrong to speak of an average or
expected revenue. Big stars and budgets affect the number of
opening engagements and shift the revenue distribution to the right.
After the opening though, a film must make it on its own and a large
number of engagements can as easily lead to rapid death as great
success. Genre has no predictive value. Present antitrust policy
regarding motion pictures is challenged by this work. Antitrust
analyses based on market share averages and industry concentration
measures are an unsuitable basis for policy because they are unstable,
reflect only the recent past, and have no predictive value. It is
dangerous to think in terms of averages about this industry.
\end{quotation}
--
Peter D. Junger--Case Western Reserve University Law School--Cleveland, OH
EMAIL: junger@samsara.law.cwru.edu URL: http://samsara.law.cwru.edu
NOTE: junger@pdj2-ra.f-remote.cwru.edu no longer exists