Summary Chapter 2

From Yochai Benkler - Wealth of Networks
Revision as of 04:08, 19 August 2007 by QdaMzs (talk | contribs)
Jump to navigation Jump to search

game boy advance sp artic blue la guerra dei gavettoni sentiero solitario s paulu adidas zip sony dcr-hc 30e regali idea regalo scacchiere ci vuole un attimo aleandro baldi mappa berlino video de decapitation de paul jonson plasma panasonic 37 tetra- bagutti midi www bahia it laser hp stampante pelletterie in firenze hard disk con lettori di schede video esecuzioni in irak www ea games it telefono rovigo vermilion nokia 3510 telefonino la torre del mangia salt un gioco di sparatutto u.d.o. thundervision never stop lumix 8 maracaibo colombo hp- officejet 7210 nuovi zombies sui nostri schermi seca residenza teo mammuccari cd quartetto pazzo stafania orlando testo my heart will go on ventose bagno archivio estrazione lotto tastiera e mouse per apple maria rosa mare vacanza puglia aereoporto linate aesop banner maker designer scaffale designjet 130 nr rich jeans microsoft windows xp media ipod speaker jbl pci-express - ati sapphire radeon x550 immagini diddl desktop www alberghi mestre sborrate con noi linch senza cravata foto carolina total request live mtv il teschio di londra inuyasha e kagome barche in vetroresina cineriz li jon lavastoviglie scomparsa totale sintoamplificatori lettore dvd jamie pressley publicinvasion semolei la fiamma the doctor rex congelatore ci100fb attrezzatura bar ariete toast mezzora dei zero assoluto vendita quadri altoparlanti ipod lansing noi siamo angeli. vol. 02 softice carmen di pietro video fotocamera per hp ipaq biebl, konstantin halmahera porno film il primo cerchio interfaccia pioneer sakmann, bert il pilota del danubio video free gay heart rata monitor pc siemens deskstar t7k250 nomi di cantanti di cartoons dawnload gioco gratis fortuna clip stato patrimoniale kojiro shout honda gold wing zubair sigla di contro campo frajese ricetrasmettitori alan 777 pescare egitto sharm vacanze www provveditorato studi milano anitra bengali elion dizionario della lingua italiana videocamere digitali canon mvx300 wallpaper gratis congresso kyoto 1997 motori stradali charlotte church. dream a dream dinerdash enz luna park - impianti turu turu condizionatore auto european society cardiothoracic surgery televisori lcd da 15 pollici charrito negro navarra mario camerini wratchild la passionaria camera brindisi panche da inversione games girl swallow nardi forno elettrico ventilato fucile cressi freakys mobile porta tv plasma da ethernet a wireless www coppaitalia it officejet all in one shame shame shame trick me wav scheda audio esterna usb creative un albero di triple seven copertina album keane masterizzatori usb lightscribe pny geforce 7800gtx 256 mb pci express francesca duranti porno negre nude the blus brothers acer al2032wm foto nide donne gratis cucardas erogatore pesca otro dia mas sin verte sanyo plv z3 orologio gucci scopa elettrica hoover a batteria sit per sole donne nvidia fx540 anker, nini roll heredia www fica nikkor af 50mm f 1 8 d registratore cd tascam immobili in zona ponte di nona roma viata omului saint john (isola delle picco... gf6600 256 cartomanzia cartomante consulto radio fan cartoni porno lettore richmond dvx team gli scarafaggi brother mfc www latinchad mediterraneo colonna sonora film ufficio lanciano festivalbar 98 taiyo yuden cartelli stradali noleggio trieste altoparlanti philips microsoft excel hyundai l17t www luca marano it camilo sesto summer madness khandagiri parmalat gigi and molly digicom usb hp all in one 1610 videoproiettori 1500 ansi lumen yamaha rx v657 inmagini di neonati lettino massaggi hi fi www ebayl it j five moderne time superstar ii - adidas half box hd esterno ide usb maglioni iceberg ==Summary of the chapter==

Overview

Information and culture are fundamentally different from standard "economic goods" such as steel and cars in two ways. First, standard goods are rival or exclusive while information is nonrival. Consider an apple: If I eat it, you cannot also eat it. If you want to eat an apple too, more resources (trees, irrigation, fertilizer, labor, etc.) will have to be expended to procure you that apple. This is not the case with information. You and I can both read this book at the same time. My consumption of the information contained in the book in no way diminishes that information or prevents others from consuming it as well. The second way in which information differs from other goods is that it is both an input and an output of its own production process. Consider a wood table: the inputs of the production process are wood, fastening devices (nails, glue), and labor. A carpenter uses these things to make the output: a table. Now consider an academic paper: The inputs are ideas and labor and these ideas are often grounded in previous academic papers. Academic papers are thus "used" in producing new academic papers.


It is these two properties of information, nonrivalry and input/output circularity, that explain why the law gives people some property-like rights over information but limits those rights in comparison to those given over other types of goods. The standard rationale for giving people property-like rights over information is that people will fail to produce information if they have no incentives to do so. Copyright, which grants the right holder a monopoly over her creation, allows her to turn information into a rival good, creating scarcity and, thus, a market for her work. That is, while the actual cost of producing a second copy of a book is marginal (it is merely the cost of photocopying the pages), copyright prevents people (through threat of sanction) from doing this without the author's permission, and thus allowing the author to control the distribution of her work.

The standard rationale for limiting the monopoly rights created by copyright and patents is that because information is both an input and an output of information, we should not allow the "building blocks" to be captured indefinitely or entirely. Thus we have time limitations on copyright, thus returning old information to its nonrival state, and "fair use" provisions, allow new producers to use otherwise protected information in certain ways and contexts (e.g., criticism, parody, news reporting).

Many economists describe the system of intellectual property as a balance of static and dynamic efficiencies: Intellectual property creates static inefficiency by artificially raising the price of information goods, but this inefficiency is balanced out, however, by gains in dynamic efficiency in form of creating an incentive for new information production.

This chapter explores whether the realities of information production fit well with standard economic theory. It argues that the efficiency of regulation information, knowledge, and cultural production through strong copyright patent is not only theoretically ambiguous but also empirically inaccurate. This chapter posits that innovation and information production is driven mostly by a mixture of (a) nonmarket sources (both public and private) and (b) market actors whose business models do not depend on the protections of intellectual property.

The chapter concludes that while granting exclusive rights-based over information provides some incentives for the future production of information, a comprehensive intellectual property regime that mimics property too closely (such as the system in both the United States and the European Union) cannot work perfectly even under ideal conditions. The upshot is that noncommercial production can often be more efficient and more important commercial production and that noncommercial production is thus moving to a more central role in our information production system.

The Diversity of Strategies in Our Current Information Production System

This section maps the variety of strategies used by information producers. The types of strategies can be divided along two axes. The first is the benefit maximization axis. At one end of this axis are information producers that rely on exclusive rights (such as patents and copyrights) to make money; at the other end, are information producers that give their information away for free in order to gain non-monetary benefits; an in the middle are information producers that aim to make money but not by relying on exclusive rights.

The second axis along which information production strategies are divided is the cost minimization axis. This axis describes the various ways in which information producers minimize the cost of the information inputs they rely on. At one end of this axis are producers who rely on public domain (i.e., free for fall) information; at the other end are information producers who barter with other producers for access to protected information (for example, small companies that form patent pools); in the middle are information producers that a) rely on information they already control, and b) purchase without reciprocity control of new information from other producers.

These two axes of three points each create nine different strategies for the production of information, which Benkler describes as follows:


The Romantic Maximizer: Relies on the public domain to minimize cost and right-based exclusion to maximize benefit. The classic example of the author writing her novel and selling it to a publisher or inventor creating a machine, patenting it, and marketing the invention.

Mickey: Relies on intrafirm strategies to minimize cost and rights-based exclusion to maximize benefit. A salient example is Walt Disney, which owns a vast number of copyrights over cartoon characters such a Mickey Mouse. Disney reuses these characters to produce derivative works or it hires animators to create new characters with the proviso that Disney will hold the copyright over these characters as well.

RCA: Relies on bartering/sharing exclusive rights to minimize cost and rights-based exclusion to maximize benefit. In the 1920s four different companies--RCA, GE, AT